Article of the Month -
December 2004
|
Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction:
Key Issues and Challenges Ahead
Klaus DEININGER, World Bank
This paper was presented for the
first time at the UN, FIG, PC IDEA Inter-regional Special Forum on The
Building of Land Information Policies in the Americas in Aguascalientes,
Mexico 26-27 October 2004
This article in .pdf-format.
Key words:
1. PROPERTY RIGHTS TO LAND
Land a key asset for the rural and urban poor that provides not only a
foundation for economic and social development but also helps to empower
them to adjust to the challenges posed by recent trends of globalization in
a number of ways. Focusing on the main forces shaping the evolution of land
rights, possible sources of tenure insecurity, and ways in which action by
the community or the government can help to reduce such insecurity and
provide a basis for more effective land utilization that will be critical
for countries to utilize the resources at their disposal in the most
effective fashion and thus promote growth as well as poverty reduction.
1.1 Origins and Evolution of Property Rights
Land rights are social conventions that regulate the distribution of the
benefits that accrue from specific uses of a certain piece of land. A number
of arguments support public provision of such rights. First, the high fixed
cost of the institutional infrastructure needed to establish and maintain
land rights favors public provision, or at least regulation. Second, the
benefits of being able to exchange land rights will be realized only in
cases where such rights are standardized and can be easily and independently
verified. Finally, without central provision, households and entrepreneurs
will be forced to spend resources to defend their claims to property, for
example through guards, fences, etc. which is not only socially wasteful but
also disproportionately disadvantages the poor, who will be the least able
to afford such expenditures.
Historically, one reason for property rights to evolve was in response to
increased payoffs from investment in more intensive use of land due to
population growth or opportunities arising from greater market integration
and technical advances. Land rights are of little importance in situations
where land is plentiful. In the course of development, the need to sustain
larger populations will require investments in land that cultivators will be
more likely to make if land rights are secure (Boserup 1965). There is
abundant evidence suggesting that, while appropriate institutional
innovations can lead to a virtuous cycle of higher population and greater
investment in land, economic growth, and increased welfare (Hayami and
Ruttan 1985). At the same time, failure of the institutions administering
land rights to respond to these demands can lead to conflict, and can
undermine societies’ productive and economic potential.
In addition to this evolution, the imposition of property rights to land
by outside forces or local overlords has affected the nature of such rights
in many countries of the developing world (Binswanger et al. 1995). The goal
of such intervention was to obtain surpluses from smallholder populations or
to force them into wage labor. To do so, a variety of mechanisms, often
supported by distortions in other markets, was used. Not surprisingly, such
imposition of rights often disrupted the evolution of land rights as a
response to population growth or has, by co-opting local institutions or
changing how they functioned, implied vast changes in the way land was
allocated and managed at the local level.
In view of the fact that the historical evolution of property rights is
not a response to purely economic forces, it is not surprising that the
arrangements found in many countries are often not the ones that would be
optimal from either an economic or a social perspective. For example, in
Africa, the vast majority of the land area is operated under customary
tenure arrangements that, until very recently, remained outside the formal
law. In Eastern Europe, collective production structures have failed to
contribute to rural growth. In Latin America and parts of Asia, highly
unequal land ownership and access to assets have made it difficult to
establish patterns of growth that are truly inclusive of the poor thereby
avoiding that growth will widen pre-existing inequalities. Despite such
shortcomings, sub-optimal and economically inefficient property rights
arrangements have often remained in place for long periods of time. In fact,
far-reaching changes of land relations have generally been confined to major
historic transitions. ** Need to indicate what are the desirable
characteristics.
1.2 Desirable Characteristics of Property Rights to Land
Property rights to land need to have a horizon long enough to provide
investment incentives and be defined in a way that makes them easy to
observe, enforce, and exchange. They need to be administered and enforced by
institutions that have both legal backing and social legitimacy and are
accessible by and accountable to the holders of property rights. Even if
property rights to land are assigned to a group, the rights and duties of
individuals within this group, and the way in which they can be modified and
will be enforced has to be clear. Also, as the precision with which property
rights are defined will tend to increase with resource values, the
institutions administering property rights need to be flexible to evolve in
response to changing requirements.
As one of the main purposes of property rights is to facilitate
investment, the duration for which such rights are awarded needs to at least
match the time frame during which returns from possible investments may
accrue. Clearly this depends on the potential for investment, which is
higher in urban than in rural areas. While indefinite property rights are
the best option, giving long-term rights that can be renewed automatically
is an alternative. Given the long time spans involved, attention to the way
in which such rights can be inherited is particularly warranted and has in
fact often proven to be critical to enhance women’s ability to control land
on their own.
Property rights to land should be defined in a way that makes them easy
to identify and exchange at a cost that is low but commensurate to the value
of the underlying land. With limited land values, low-cost mechanisms of
identifying boundaries, such as physical marks (hedges, rivers, and trees)
that are recognized by the community, will generally suffice while higher
resource values will require more precise and costly means of demarcation.
Similarly, where land is relatively plentiful and transactions are
infrequent, low-cost mechanisms to record transactions, such as witnessing
by community elders will be appropriate. More formal mechanisms will
normally be adopted once transactions become more frequent and start to go
across traditional boundaries of community and kinship.
The key advantage of formal, as compared to informal, property rights is
that those holding formal rights can call on the power of the state to
enforce their rights. For this to be feasible, the institutions involved
need to enjoy legal backing as well as social legitimacy, including
accountability to and accessibility by the local population. Yet in many
countries, especially in Africa, the gap between legality and legitimacy has
been a major source of friction, something that is illustrated by the fact
that in Africa overall more than 90% of land remain outside the existing
legal system. Failure to give legal backing to land administration
institutions that enjoy social legitimacy can undermine their ability to
draw on anything more than informal mechanisms for enforcement. By contrast,
institutions that are legal but do not enjoy social recognition may make
little difference to the lives of ordinary people and have therefore often
proven to be highly ineffective. Bringing legality and legitimacy together
is a major challenge for policy that can not be solved in the abstract.
Whether it is more appropriate to give property rights to individuals or
to a group will depend on the nature of the resource and on existing social
arrangements. Group rights will be useful in situations characterized by
economies of scale in resource management or if externalities exist that can
be managed at the level of the group but not the individual. The advantage
of group, as compared with individual, land rights will generally decrease
in the course of development because of a number of factors. Technical
progress reduces the risk of crop failure while at the same time increasing
the potential payoff from investments; development of the nonfarm economy
provides access to more predictable income streams and greater access to
physical infrastructure reduces not only the risk, but also the cost, of
publicly providing property rights. Thus one would expect to see a move
toward more individualized forms of property rights with economic
development. At the same time transformation of property toward increased
individualization is not automatic. On the contrary, it will be affected by
political and economic factors, and thus often coincide with major
conflicts, upheavals, or power struggles.
Exogenous demographic changes, especially in the absence of economic
development, can increase the scarcity and value of land. This can challenge
traditional authorities and institutions who, earlier, had unquestioned
authority over land allocation and resolution of disputes. Land conflicts
often generate large, negative, external effects that can undermine the
state’s authority and effectiveness by setting up a multiplicity of parallel
institutions, as illustrated by the fact that unresolved land conflicts have
in some cases escalated into an important contributor to state failure. To
avoid this, the institutions managing land rights will need to be able to
re-interpret traditions and social norms authoritatively and in a way that
protects the poor and vulnerable from abuse of their rights by those with
political power and economic resources.
2.2 Evidence on the Impact of Tenure Security
In many countries of the developing world, insecure land tenure prevents
large parts of the population from realizing the economic and non-economic
benefits such as greater investment incentives, transferability of land, and
improved credit market access, more sustainable management of resources, and
independence from discretionary interference by bureaucrats, that are
normally associated with secure property rights to land. More than 50
percent of the peri-urban population in Africa and more than 40 percent in
Asia live under informal tenure and therefore have highly insecure land
rights. While no such figures are available for rural areas, rural land
users are reported to make considerable investments in land as a way to
increase tenure security (Platteau 2000, Otsuka 2001), illustrating that
tenure security is highly valued.
A first benefit from increased tenure security that can easily be
measured is the increase in land users’ investment incentives. Some studies
have reported a doubling of investment, and values for land with more secure
tenure are reported to be between 30 and 80 percent above those for land
where there is a higher probability of losing land (Feder 2002).
Transferability of land will increase this effect and is important in
situations where the scope for transacting land between less and more
productive producers has increased, for example, because of increased
development of the nonagricultural economy and rural-urban migration
(Deininger et al. 2003). Higher tenure security will also reduce the time
and resources individuals need to spend on securing their land rights,
allowing them to invest these resources elsewhere.
Finally, where effective demand for credit exists, giving formal title to
land can help producers gain access to credit and improve the functioning of
financial markets. It has long been noted that the impact of such credit
access may be differentiated by size of landholdings and that therefore
attention to the anticipated equity effects will be required (Carter and
Olinto 2003). In situations where the credit effect associated with title is
unlikely to materialize in the near future, a more gradual and lower-cost
approach to securing land rights and improving tenure security, with the
possibility of upgrading once the need arises, will allow provision of most,
if not all, the benefits from increased tenure security at lower cost.
Ensuring secure land tenure will be of particular relevance for groups
who were traditionally discriminated against. Attention to women’s rights
will be warranted where women are the main cultivators, where out-migration
is high or control of productive activities is differentiated by gender, or
where adult mortality and unclear inheritance regulations undermine women’s
livelihood if their husband dies, as in Africa with HIV/AIDS (Deininger &
Castagnini 2002).
2.3 Ways to Increase Tenure Security
The findings described in the previous section imply that governments
have a role to play in providing secure tenure to owners and users of land.
Even though formal title will increase tenure security in many situations,
experience indicates that it is not always necessary, and often not a
sufficient condition for optimum use of the land resource. The goal of
providing tenure security for the long term, administered in a
cost-effective way through institutions that combine legality with social
legitimacy can be achieved in a variety of ways, depending on the situation.
In customary systems, legal recognition of existing rights and
institutions, subject to minimum conditions, is often more effective than
premature attempts at establishing formalized structures. Legally
recognizing customary land rights subject to a determination of membership
and the codification or establishment of internal rules and mechanisms for
conflict resolution can greatly enhance occupants’ security. Demarcation of
the boundaries of community land can remove the threat of encroachment by
outsiders while drawing to well-defined procedures within the community to
assign rights within the group. Conflicts historically often erupt first in
conjunction with land transfers, especially with outsiders. Where such
transfers occur and are socially accepted, the terms should be recorded in
writing to avoid ambiguity that could subsequently lead to land-related
conflict (Lavigne Delville et al. 2002).
Occupants on state land have often made considerable efforts to
increase their level of security, in some cases through significant
investments, but often remain vulnerable to eviction threats. Due to their
limited land rights they often cannot make full use of the land they occupy.
Giving them legal rights and regularizing their possession is therefore
important, along with ensuring that appropriate means are in place for
resolving any conflicts that may arise in the process. In many situations,
political or other considerations may preclude the award of full private
property rights. If existing institutions can credibly commit to lease
contracts, giving users secure, transferable, long-term lease rights will
permit realization of most, if not all, the investment benefits associated
with tenure security. In these cases, recognition of long-term peaceful
occupation in good faith (adverse possession) and award of long-term land
leases with provisions for automatic renewal will be the most desirable
option. If the leases awarded by state institutions are not credible, full
privatization may be required to give users sufficient security of tenure
and the associated benefits. An indicator for limited credibility of leases
is that financial institutions will not accept long-term leases as
collateral, despite strong demand for credit.
Where individual title will be the option of choice,
inefficiencies in the land administration institutions are responsible for
demarcation of boundaries, registration and record keeping, adjudication of
rights, and resolution of conflict can still preclude the realization of
many of the benefits of secure tenure. If these institutions are not working
well, are poorly coordinated, inefficient, or corrupt, transaction costs
will increase thus reducing the level of transactions below what would be
socially optimal and in many cases excluding the poorer completely. In the
extreme, lack of clarity about who is responsible for specific areas or
infighting between institutions has evolved into a major source of
insecurity that undermined the value and authority of titles or certificates
of land ownership that were distributed. In such situations, institutional
reform, including improved coordination within the government and with the
private sector, will be a precondition for the state’s ability to
effectively deliver property rights.
Even though most countries mandate equality of men and women before the
law in principle, the procedures used by land administration institutions
often discriminate against women, explicitly or implicitly. To overcome
this, a pro-active stance in favor of awarding land rights to women by
governments, together with rigorous evaluation of innovative approaches
aiming to accomplish greater gender equality in control of conjugal land on
the ground would be warranted.
3. LAND TRANSACTIONS
Even though rural dwellers normally access land through a wide variety of
different channels (de Janvry et al. 2001), land transactions can play an
important role by allowing those who are productive but are either landless
or own little land to access land. Land markets also facilitate the exchange
of land as the off-farm economy develops and, where the conditions for doing
so exist, provide a basis for the use of land as collateral in credit
markets. Capital market imperfections and policy distortions have, in many
instances, prevented land sales markets from contributing to increased
levels of productivity or reduced poverty. This has led some observers to
take a negative stance on any type of land market activity and to support
government intervention in land markets, despite the considerable scope of
rental markets and the evidence on limited effectiveness of government
intervention in such markets.
3.1 Conceptual Foundations
To understand why in some cases land transactions may fail to contribute
to improving productivity and equity, it is necessary to review the
conceptual foundations that underlie the operation of land markets and how
some of the market imperfections frequently encountered in rural areas of
the developing world will have a differential impact on land rental and
sales.
Imperfections in labor and credit markets, and the scope of economies of
scale in production, will affect the way in which land markets function. A
large literature has demonstrated that unmechanized agriculture generally
does not exhibit economies of scale in production (Carter 1984, Benjamin
1995, Deininger and Feder 2001), even though economies of scale from
marketing may in some cases be transferred back to the production stage . At
the same time, the need to closely supervise hired laborers implies that
owner-operated farms are more efficient than those that rely predominantly
on large numbers of permanent wage workers. However, rationing and
collateral will be needed to overcome imperfections that are inherent to
credit markets. This favors farmers who own larger amounts of land, and in
environments where access to credit is important, can lead to the appearance
of a positive relationship between farm size and productivity, possibly
counteracting the supervision cost advantage of small owner-operated farms.
These factors will have different implications for rental as compared to
sales markets.
Rental markets are characterized by low transaction costs and, in most
cases where rent is paid on an annual basis, require only a limited initial
capital outlay. This, together with participants’ ability to adjust contract
terms so as to overcome market failures in capital and other markets,
implies that rental is a more flexible and versatile means of transferring
land from less to more productive producers than sales markets (Sadoulet et
al. 2001). Renting is thus more likely to improve overall productivity and,
in addition, can provide a stepping stone for tenants to accumulate
experience and possibly make the transition to land ownership at a later
stage.
The importance of tenure security for rental markets is illustrated by
the fact that, where land tenure is perceived to be insecure, long term
contracts are unlikely to be entered in. In fact, relatively insecure tenure
has been claimed to be one of the key reasons for the virtual absence of
long-term rental contracts in most countries of Latin America.
The literature has long pointed out that rental arrangements based on
fixed rather than share rent are more likely to maximize productivity. Poor
producers may, however, not be offered fixed rent contracts because of the
risk of default. In these circumstances, sharecropping has emerged as a
second-best solution. Whether or not sharecropping contracts are associated
with sizeable inefficiencies and whether government action could lead to an
improvement has been subject to considerable discussion. In practice, the
efficiency losses associated with sharecropping contracts were found to be
relatively small, and improving on them through government intervention has
proven to be difficult, if not impossible. In view of the fact that the
contracting parties have considerable flexibility to adjust contract
parameters so as to avoid inefficiencies, for example by entering into long
term relationships or through close supervision, the general view is that
prohibition of sharecropping or other forms of rental contracts is unlikely
to improve productivity (Otsuka et al. 1992). The welfare impact of rental
contracts depends on the terms of the contract, which in turn are affected
by the outside options open particularly to the weaker party. Efforts to
expand the range of options available to tenants, e.g. via access to
infrastructure and non-agricultural labor markets, are likely to have a more
beneficial impact on land rental market outcomes and rural productivity than
prohibition of certain options.
Transfer of land use rights through rental markets can go a long way
towards improving productivity and welfare in rural economies. At the same
time, the ability to transfer ownership of land will be required to use land
as collateral in credit markets, and thus to provide the basis for low-cost
operation of financial markets. This advantage comes at the cost that sales
markets will be more affected than rental markets by imperfections in credit
markets as well as by other distortions such as subsidies to agriculture.
Activity in land sales markets will depend on participants’ expectations
regarding future price movements, creating a potential for asset price
bubbles that are not justified by the underlying productive value as well as
a tendency towards speculative land acquisition by the wealthy in
anticipation of major capital gains. Ample historical evidence also shows
that in risky environments where small landowners do not have access to
credit markets, distress sales of land by the poor can occur, with
consequent negative equity and efficiency impacts over time. The impact of
such distress sales is magnified by the fact that, where, as in most rural
areas, land sales markets are thin, land prices can fluctuate considerably
over time. High transaction costs associated with land sales, which are
often further increased by government intervention, can result in the
segmentation of such markets whereby certain strata only deal with each
other or sales remain informal. All these factors imply that land
acquisition by the poor through the land sales market will be difficult, and
that as a consequence, the potential for productivity-enhancing land
redistribution through sales markets is likely to be very limited.
3.2 Policy Implications
To realize the full benefits that can accrue from rental markets,
governments need to ensure that tenure security is high enough to facilitate
long-term contracts, and eliminate unjustified restrictions on the operation
of such markets. Limitations on the operation of land sales markets may, in
some cases, be justified on theoretical grounds. In practice, efforts to
implement such restrictions have almost invariably weakened property rights
with the result that often the unintended negative consequences of sales
market restrictions have far outweighed the positive impacts they were
intended to achieve. With few exceptions in the case of rapid structural
change, there is little to recommend such restrictions as an effective tool
for policy.
Short-term rental contracts will only provide limited incentives for
users to undertaken land-related investment. For longer-term contracts to be
feasible, long duration of land rights and high levels of tenure security
are critical and finding ways to ensure such tenure security is a key policy
issue. Another constraint on land rental markets has been the imposition of
rent ceilings or the award of implicit ownership rights to tenants. While
effectively implemented tenancy regulation can benefit sitting tenants, it
is costly and may thus not be an efficient way of transferring resources to
the poor, even in the short term. In the longer term, such restrictions will
reduce the supply of land available to the rental market and undermine
investment, directly hurting the poor. Evidence from countries that have
eliminated such restrictions suggests that doing so can improve access to
land via rental markets and increase households’ participation in the
nonfarm labor market and, by reducing the discretionary power of
bureaucrats, improve governance. A policy issue is thus how to sequence the
elimination of such restrictions in a way that does not undermine equity
and, in particular, protects sitting tenants.
Credit market imperfections will affect the functioning of sales markets
and may lead to situations where government intervention could, in a
hypothetical world of perfect implementation, lead to outcomes that would
improve efficiency and equity. Implementing such interventions has, however,
proved to be exceedingly difficult in practice. In the vast majority of
cases restrictions on land sales markets have undermined tenure security and
ended up making things worse than they were at the outset.
Restrictions on the transferability of land imposed by a central
authority have generally limited credit access and often only pushed such
transactions into informality. Except in situations of rapid economic
transition, they are unlikely to be justified. Local communities are more
likely to be able to appreciate the costs of limiting the transferability of
land to outsiders or the benefits of eliminating them than central
government bureaucrats. As long as such decisions are reached in a
transparent way, aware of costs and benefits, allowing communities to decide
on whether to maintain or drop the restrictions on land transactions with
outsiders that generally characterize customary systems of land tenure may
be more effective than unenforceable central restrictions.
Land ownership ceilings have generally been ineffective as a means to
facilitate the breakup of large farms, and instead have led to red tape,
spurious subdivisions, and corruption (Appu 1997). Where they were low, they
have apparently had a negative impact on investment and land owners’ ability
to access credit, as in the Philippines. The only situation where they can
be justified is where high enough land ceilings may help to limit the
speculative acquisition of land, something that may be relevant in some CIS
countries.
High levels of fragmentation, caused either by successive subdivision in
the course of inheritance or by the desire to award at least one plot of a
specific quality or use type to each producer in the process of land
distribution, are often thought to lead to inefficiencies in agricultural
production. The magnitude and importance of such inefficiencies increases as
agricultural production becomes more mechanized. Dealing with fragmentation
case by case based on individual initiative may incur high costs of
negotiation, something that has provided the justification for governments
to adopt programs to complement market mechanisms in an effort to facilitate
more rapid consolidation of holdings at lower costs. Although high benefits
from such programs are reported from Western Europe, the programs have been
slow. Evidence from China highlights that, in environments where
administrative capacity is limited, programs aiming at consolidation can run
into great difficulties and fail to yield the expected benefits. Rigorous
evaluation of the costs and benefits of different approaches to
consolidation in Eastern Europe would be very desirable and will be required
before wider adoption of such measures can be recommended.
4. SOCIALLY DESIRABLE LAND USE
Decentralized transactions based on secure land rights are likely to be
more conducive to efficiency and equity while offering less scope for
corruption and other undesirable side effects than administrative
intervention, especially as the number of exchanges increases and the
contractual details become more complex. At the same time, governments have
a clear role to play in a number of respects. Government needs to help
establish the legal and institutional framework within which land markets
can function and create a policy environment that rewards transactions which
will increase productivity and welfare rather than the opposite. Where the
land distribution is highly unequal and large amounts of productive land are
un- or underutilized, governments may find it necessary to deal with
fundamental issues related to the distribution of asset endowments which
markets will not be able to address. Governments have fiscal and regulatory
instruments at their disposal to provide incentives for land use that
maximizes social welfare, for example by helping to internalize effects that
are external to individual land users. Their lack of administrative capacity
notwithstanding, many developing countries rely disproportionately on a
regulatory approach, often with the result of encouraging discretionary
bureaucratic behavior. Awareness of the rationale for specific intervention,
the different mechanisms and the most appropriate level for doing so can
help to promote an approach that could produce more satisfactory outcomes,
both in terms of compliance, and in terms of reducing the red tape private
entrepreneurs have to deal with.
4.1 Land Reform
The fact that in many countries the current land ownership distribution
has its origins in discriminatory policies rather than in market forces has
long provided a justification for adopting policies aimed at land reform.
The record of such policies is mixed. Land reforms have been very successful
in Asia (Japan, Korea, Taiwan [China]) and positive impacts have been
reported from some African countries such as Kenya and Zimbabwe in the early
phases of their post-independence land reforms (Gunning and et al 2000, King
1977, Jeon and Kim 2000). At the same time, land reforms in Latin America
failed to live up to their objectives and remain incomplete in many respects
(de Janvry and Sadoulet 1989). A key reason for such limited impact was that
reforms were often guided by short-term political objectives, and that an
“agrarian” emphasis on full-time farming increased their cost while reducing
the number of potential beneficiaries and the reforms’ impact on poverty.
Where extreme inequality in the land distribution and underutilization of
vast tracts of productive land co-exist with deep rural poverty, a case for
redistributive measures to increase access to land by the poor can be made,
both politically and from an economic perspective. Even in such cases, a
number of different instruments (ranging from expropriation with
compensation to activation of rental markets) to affect the transfer of land
will normally be appropriate and, to ensure productive use of the land, land
reform needs to be combined with other programs at the government’s
disposal. To ensure success, access to nonland assets and working capital
and a conducive policy environment are essential (Deininger 1999). Those
benefiting from land reform need to be able to access output markets as well
as credit, the selection of beneficiaries needs to be transparent and
participatory, and attention needs to be paid to the fiscal viability of
land reform efforts.
Governments are more likely to meet these challenges if they use the
mechanisms at their disposal in concert and with the objective of maximizing
synergies between them. This also implies a need to integrate land reform
into the broader context of economic and social policies aimed at
development and poverty reduction, and to implement programs in a
decentralized way with maximum participation by potential beneficiaries and
at least some grant element. Given the continuing relevance of the issue,
the often heated political debate surrounding it, and the lack of
quantitative evidence on some more recent approaches, rigorous, open, and
participatory evaluation of ongoing experiences is particularly important.
4.2 Land Conflict
Increasing scarcity of land in the presence of high rates of population
growth, possibly along with a historical legacy of discrimination and highly
unequal land access, implies that many historical and contemporaneous
conflicts have their roots in struggles over land. This suggests a special
role for land policy in many postconflict settings. An ability to deal with
land claims by women and refugees, to use land as part of a strategy to
provide economic opportunities to demobilized soldiers, and to resolve
conflicts and overlapping claims to land in a legitimate manner, will
greatly increase the scope for postconflict reconciliation and speedy
recovery of the productive sector, a key for subsequent economic growth.
Failure to put in place the necessary mechanisms can keep conflicts
simmering, either openly or under the surface, with high social and economic
costs especially because, as time goes by subsequent transactions will lead
to a multiplication of the number of conflicts which can result in
generalized insecurity of land tenure.
Although discussion of the issue in the literature is still limited, even
comparatively “minor” conflict over land can significantly reduce
productivity and, as it is likely to affect the poor disproportionately,
equity (Deininger and Castagnini 2002). Such conflicts are likely in
situations of rapid demographic or economic transition. In such cases
existing institutions must have the authority and legitimacy to re-interpret
rules and thereby prevent relatively minor conflicts from evolving into
large-scale confrontation. Instead of opening up parallel channels for
conflict resolution, something that has often contributed to increasing
rather than reducing the incidence of land-related conflict, building on
informal institutions that have social legitimacy and can deal with
conflicts at low cost may be preferable.
4.3 Land Taxation
Local governments’ lack of adequate sources of own revenue may affect not
only their financial viability, but also limit their responsiveness and
accountability to the local population. Land taxes have long been identified
as a source of own revenue for local governments that is associated with
minimal distortions and at the same time can encourage more intensive land
use. Even though the extent to which land taxes are used varies widely
across countries, actual revenues are generally well below their potential.
Reasons for this include deficient incentive structures and neglect of
issues relating to assessment, tax administration, and tax rate setting, in
addition to the political difficulty of having significant land taxes.
The high visibility of land taxes implies that establishing them may be
difficult politically, especially in settings where landlords still wield
considerable political power. In addition to democratic election of local
governments and administrative support to the different aspects of tax
collection, schemes to encourage fiscal responsibility and tax collection at
the local level, for example a matching of taxes collected with central
funds, can help to appropriately design and subsequently collect land taxes.
This can have a significant impact on incentives for effective land use,
local government revenues, the type and level of public services provided,
and governance.
4.4 State Land Ownership and Land Use Regulations
In many developing countries, the state has proven not to have the
capacity to bring land to its best use. Nonetheless, surprisingly large
tracts of land continue to be under state ownership or management. In
peri-urban areas, unoccupied land of high potential often lacks investment
and is subject to bureaucratic red tape, nontransparent processes of
allocation, and corruption. Experience demonstrates that privatization of
such land could not only yield significant amounts of resources for local
governments, but also increase investment and the effectiveness of land use.
If public land has been occupied by poor people in good faith for a long
time and significant improvements have been made, such rights should be
recognized and formalized at a nominal cost to avoid negative equity
outcomes . In cases where state land of high potential, especially in urban
areas, is unoccupied, auctioning it off to the highest bidder will be the
option of choice, especially if the proceeds can be used to compensate
original land owners or to provide land and services to the poor at the
urban fringes at much lower cost.
Governments should have the right of compulsory land acquisition, with
compensation, for broader public benefit. At the same time, the way in which
many developing country governments exercise this right, especially for
urban expansion, undermines tenure security and, as often little or no
compensation is paid, also has negative impacts on equity. In a number of
cases anticipation of expropriation without compensation has led landowners
to sell their land in informal markets at low prices, thereby not only
forcing them to part with a key assets at a fraction of its real value but
also encouraging unplanned development and urban sprawl that will make
subsequent provision of services by the government harder and more costly.
The disappointing experience with state management of land has led to a
general preference for regulation in order to reduce undesirable
externalities, to help maintain availability of public goods such as
landscapes, historical values, or to facilitate more effective provision of
services by the government. Where externalities from land use arise, limits
on landowners’ discretion with respect to land use are justified. The
questions that need to be answered in trying to deal with these are whether
such measures should be imposed by central or local authorities and how
specific interventions should be designed.
In general, zoning and other land use regulations should be established
based on a clear assessment of the capacity needed to implement them, the
costs of doing so, and the way in which both costs and benefits will be
distributed. Failure to do so has often implied that centrally imposed
regulations could either not be implemented with existing capacity, that
doing so was associated with very high cost that were predominantly borne by
the poor, or that they degenerated into a source of rent seeking. Too little
thought has often been given to providing mechanisms that would allow local
communities to deal with such externalities in a more decentralized and
therefore less costly way. Gradual devolution of responsibility for land use
regulation to local governments, if coupled with capacity building, could
make a significant contribution to efforts towards more effective
decentralization.
5. CONCLUSION: PUTTING LAND INTO A BROADER POLICY CONTEXT
Land policy addresses structural issues which, in the longer term, will
need to be addressed in order to ensure that the economic opportunities
opened by other policies changes will benefit the broad majority of the
poor. Measures to increase land tenure security, reduce the transaction of
transferring land rights, and establish a regulatory framework to prevent
undesirable externalities do, however, cut across traditional boundaries
with institutional responsibilities dispersed among ministries, e.g.
environment, land reform, urban planning, and lack of coordination and
capacity. To overcome compartmentalization that may result from such
arrangements, it will be essential to have a long term vision and to include
land issues in the framework of a broadly backed development strategy. The
extent to which goals are achieved should be monitored independently, and
jointly with other government programs aimed at poverty reduction and
economic development.
In addition to cutting across institutional boundaries, issues of land
policy are complex, country-specific, of a long-term nature, and often
controversial politically. This demands particular attention to the
sequencing of reforms as well as their political economy. Even if
land-related interventions will make society better off, they may be
challenged by vested interests who derive considerable benefits from the
status quo. To make policy reform feasible, an open and broadly based policy
dialogue, carefully chosen and evaluated pilots, and sharing of experience
across countries will be essential and can at the same time help build local
capacity for policy formulation and implementation.
REFERENCES
Appu, P. S. 1997. Land Reforms in India: A Survey of Policy, Legislation
and Implementation. New Delhi: Vikas Publishing House.
Benjamin, D. 1995. "Can Unobserved Land Quality Explain the Inverse
Productivity Relationship?" Journal of Development Economics 46 (1): 51-84.
Binswanger, H. P., K. Deininger and G. Feder. 1995. "Power, Distortions,
Revolt and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations." Handbook of development
economics.Volume 3B (1995): 2659-2772 2659-772.
Boserup, E. 1965. Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of
Agrarian Change Under Population Pressure. New York: Aldine Publishing Co.
Carter, M. R. 1984. "Identification of the Inverse Relationship between
Farm Size and Productivity: An Empirical Analysis of Peasant Agricultural
Production." Oxford Economic Papers 36 (1): 131-45.
Carter, M. R. and P. Olinto. 2003. "Getting Institutions "Right" for
Whom? Credit Constraints and the Impact of Property Rights on the Quantity
and Composition of Investment." American Journal of Agricultural Economics
85 (1): 173-86.
de Janvry, A., G. Gordillo, J. P. Platteau and E. Sadoulet. 2001. Access
to Land, Rural Poverty, and Public Action. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
de Janvry, A. and E. Sadoulet. 1989. "A Study in Resistance to
Institutional Change: The Lost Game of Latin American Land Reform." World
Development 17 (9): 1397-407.
Deininger, K. 1999. "Making Negotiated Land Reform Work: Initial
Experience from Colombia, Brazil and South Africa." World Development 27
(4): 651-72.
Deininger, K. and R. Castagnini. 2002. "Incidence and Impact of Land
Conflict in Uganda." World Bank Discussion Paper, Washington, D.C.
Deininger, K. and G. Feder. 2001. "Land Institutions and Land Markets."
Handbook of Agricultural Economics (B.Gardner and G.Raussser, Eds) 288-331.
Deininger, K., S. Jin, B. Adenew, S. Gebre-Selassie, and B. Nega. 2003.
"Tenure Security and Land-Related Investment: Evidence from Ethiopia." World
Bank Policy Research Paper 2991. Washington DC: World Bank.
Feder, G. 2002. "The Intricacies of Land Markets: Why the World Bank
Succeeds in Economic Reform through Land Registration and Tenure Security."
Paper presented at the Conference of the International Federation of
Surveyors, April 19-26, 2002, Washington DC .
Gunning, J. W. and et al. 2000. "Revisiting Forever Gained: Income
Dynamics in the Resettlement Areas of Zimbabwe, 1983-96." Journal of
Development Studies 36 (6): 131-54.
Hayami, Y. and V. W. Ruttan. 1985. "Agricultural Development: An
International Perspective." Johns Hopkins University Press Baltimore.
Jeon, Y. D. and Y. Y. Kim. 2000. "Land Reform, Income Redistribution, and
Agricultural Production in Korea." Economic Development and Cultural Change
48 (2): 253-68.
King, R. 1977. Land Reform: a World Survey. London: G.Bell and Sons.
Lavigne Delville, P., C. Toulmin, J.-P. Colin and J.-P. Chauveau. 2002.
Negotiating Acces to Land in West Africa: A Synthesis of Findings from
Research on Derived Rights to Land. London: IIED/GRET.
Otsuka, K. 2001. Land Tenure and Natural Resource Management: A
Comparative Study of Agrarian Communities in Asia and Africa Baltimore and
London: Johns Hopkins University Press for the International Food Policy
Research Institute.
Otsuka, K., H. Chuma and Y. Hayami. 1992. "Land and Labor Contracts in
Agrarian Economies: Theories and Facts." Journal of Economic Literature 30
(4): 1965-2018.
Platteau, J. P. 2000. Institutions, Social Norms, and Economic
Development Fundamentals of Development Economics, vol. 1. Reading, U.K.:
Harwood Academic.
Sadoulet, E., R. Murgai and A. de Janvry. 2001. "Access to Land via Land
Rental Markets." In de Janvry, A., G. Gordillo, J.-P. Platteau and E.
Sadoulet, eds., Access to Land Rural Poverty and Public Action. Oxford:
Oxford University Press .
CONTACTS
Klaus Deininger
World Bank - MSN 3505
1818 H St. NW
Washington DC, 20433
USA
Fax + 1 202 522 1150
Email: Kdeininger@worldbank.org
|